th birthday, to find a copy of the British edition of Globalization and Its Discontents on his bed. I turned it over to display my contribution, and found that the blurb had been shortened to something like, “This is a good book. Read it.” More seriously, my name had also been shortened, to those two initials that for obvious reasons I never use: J.K. ... Galbraith.A few challenges for the future of U.S. economic policy
James K. Galbraith
Remarks to the Festschrift Conference Honoring Joe Stiglitz at Sixty
October 25, 2003.
I am especially honored to be here today. I arrived at Yale too late to have been a student of Joe Stiglitz. I am not his coauthor, in neither the first nor the second degree of co-authorial consanguinity. We did not overlap in government. On the other hand, I did blurb his book. And so, I was very pleased last week, on a visit to my father in Cambridge to celebrate his 95
My father’s reaction was immediate:
“That’s just fine.” And then he said something that I hesitate to repeat.
But I think it is best viewed as something that a writer of a certain
caliber would only say to a peer. “Tell Stiglitz,” he said to me, “that he
can look forward to the day, thirty-five years from now, when he will have
achieved his mature style.”
I have taken my brief today to comment on the future of all
of American economic policy, and I have broken down my remarks into five
categories.
I. Up from NAIRU.
When Joe Stiglitz was Chair of the
Council of Economic Advisers, back in the last Golden Age, there were
economists who believed that six percent unemployment or thereabouts was a
magic threshold, below which inflation would accelerate without limit.
Yet there were also dissenters, such as Bill Vickrey of this University, who
won a Nobel Prize in the last days of his life, and Bob Eisner who should
have.
Faced with the conflict between high theory and low reality,
Joe struck an artful balance. Yes, he said, NAIRU was an important
concept, deeply integrated into the models then used at the CEA. But
II. Getting Over Budget Balance
Late in the Golden Age, after Stiglitz
had decamped to the Bank, there were economists in high positions who
believed, or pretended to believe, that it would be possible for the federal
government to run budget surpluses indefinitely, even eliminating the entire
burden (so it was called) of the federal debt. “Fiscal drag” had been
forgotten. When I mentioned the concept at a conference at the White House
in April, 2000, the main reaction was a nervous titter.
Today we are (here I should perhaps say, “I am”) grateful for
federal budget deficits near a half trillion dollars, just to keep the
economy afloat. A new boom would probably require even larger deficits --
and with war at hand, who is to say we will not get them? “Stimulus” is a
word spoken openly even by the Chair of a Republican Council of Economic
Advisers, whose pet dog at one time was named Keynes. This is progress, I
suppose.
Yet progress is threatened by the political habit of always
looking at future fiscal decisions in terms of return toward budget balance,
and not in terms of growth and progress toward full employment. In the
budget process the economy is assumed; the goal of policy is to fit what
needs to be done within the framework of falling deficits and eventual
return to balance.. Needless to say, not very much in the public social
sphere can ever be achieved this way. And particularly not, when one party
has learned to game the system by reducing taxes on capital wealth year
after year.
Fiscal federalism complicates these difficulties.
Constitutional rules that state and localities balance their budgets have
converted much public activity from counter- to procyclical. And it is also
possible for regressive federal tax cuts to force regressive state and local
tax increases and cuts in public services directly, with the public scarcely
aware of the connection. A new program of intergovernmental fiscal
assistance, providing stabilizing federal funds for essential public
services, should be high on the emergency list.
The broader solution? Surely it is for responsible political
leaders and economists working with them to refocus policy around tangible
objectives, of which full employment is only one. Others must relate to
social goals, for public health, education, transportation and energy and in
other fields. When these goals are set and the price of meeting them is
determined, the question then becomes: what budget is compatible with
achieving them at high levels of employment? People will pay taxes--and
support deficits that finance investments--for a purpose. Or so let us hope.
III. Facing Up to Private Debt.
The macroeconomists of the 1940s, 50s and
60s were fortunate in that depression and war had placed the American
household sector on a strong financial basis, with liquid assets and little
debt. The United States was also the world’s great creditor with an
overpowering position in trade. From this starting point it was sensible to
think of hydraulic models, of stimulus and restraint, working in an
environment of occasional shocks to demand or supply. Fiscal policy drove
consumer spending; monetary policy regulated business investment. Anyway
that was good enough for a textbook approximation.
That world no longer exists. After the Keynesian Devolution,
households now borrow and invest, and their effective demand is regulated as
much by interest rates as by taxes. The power of monetary policy depends in
part on the stock of household debt, and on the burden of personal interest
payments in relation to income. Moreover, the United States is no longer a
net creditor to the world, and runs a vast current account deficit at full
employment.
How important are these factors? Is Wynne Godley right in
emphasizing the mid-term reversion-to-normalcy of household acquisition of
financial assets? Godley’s analysis proved a useful guide to the recent
recession. Its main implication now is that even more enormous federal
budget deficits will be required to offset the public’s financial
preferences and leakages abroad. Without this, are we doomed to a sluggish
expansion? Or will a new boom psychology sweep away the current mood of
financial restraint? I do not know, and time will tell. Meanwhile, it would
be good to have a few more economists working on this issue.
IV. New Economy, Oil Economy, War Economy.
To mention another unfashionable name, my
friend the late Walt Rostow was a champion of sector economics – that middle
ether of commodities, technology and energy, suspended between micro and
macro, that most of us do not breathe. To most economists these are
conceptualized as shocks. And a shock is unexamined, merely measured and
classified as either positive or negative, supply or demand. But in a world
governed by shocks, it would be useful to have economists who know something
about how to control them.
We allowed ourselves to be hoodwinked during the technology
boom, to convert in our imaginations a financial melee into a scientific
marvel. The financial interpretation of this phenomenon would have been
quite easy to understand – perhaps even to remedy by regulatory
intervention, a point to which Joe called attention yesterday with his
reference to margin requirements, which could have been raised by the
Federal Reserve on its own authority under Regulation T. The other
interpretation was to a large degree illusory and therefore impenetrable,
and it is not surprising that it remains very poorly understood.
Now that we have been once again drawn into the vortex of
oil, it would be good to have sorted out the geography and economics of
energy supply, substitution, conservation, and the control of carbon
emissions and climate change. Scientific work on these issues has advanced
since I was in graduate school, at which time making fun of the Club of Rome
was an indoor sport. Economists have not kept up; the facile architecture of
emissions trading is not a sufficient contribution for our profession to
have made to this field.
The challenge of reducing war and violence is central to
economic development. Policy economists used to know a great deal about war
– the costs of war, the effects of bombing, how best to avoid the use of
nuclear weapons. Today, too few concern themselves seriously with these
issues. More are welcome to do so. The first step is to join Economists
Allied for Arms Reduction, at
V. Inequality, Development, and the Financial Future
Finally, the United States needs stable
economic development in the wider world. Rising inequality worldwide (yes,
it is rising) and financial instability threaten our export markets, the
stability of our population structure (because inequality promotes
migration), and our health. Ultimately they will undermine the dollar-based
financial system we have enjoyed as the world’s consumer of last resort for
the past thirty years. Beyond this, the problems of the wider world engage
us on moral grounds, about which much more could be said but not in this
space.
I mention this issue partly to call attention to a theme of
my own, namely that global inequality is much easier to measure than most
suppose. And when one does so, filling in gaps and fixing problems by
statistical means, one finds that the pattern of change in global inequality
is closely related to macroeconomic events, notably high interest rates and
the debt crises of the 1980s and 1990s. In this way, one can begin to break
down the barriers between macro- and microeconomics, by showing that
macroeconomic and monetary events are not distributively neutral.
(1)
Joe Stiglitz is a sharp critic of mis-governed
globalization, beginning with striking insight into the Russian disaster of
the 1990s. He has called for regional financial stabilization measures along
the lines of Sakakibara’s1997 Asian Monetary Fund, vetoed by the U.S.
Treasury at that time. The AMF and similar ideas to regulate capital flow
remain a promising way forward, and the discussion around them should not
die away. The next generation of international policy economists will
inherit the job of putting it all together in practice. Once again, it would
be a good if a few more of this generation turned their attention to how
this might best be done.
***
James Galbraith holds the Lloyd M. Bentsen Chair in Government/Business Relations at the LBJ School of Public Affairs, the University of Texas at Austin. He is a Senior Scholar at the Levy Institute and is Chair, Economists Allied for Arms Reduction.
__________________________________________
(1) Michael Rothschild yesterday
described how Google functions as a new mechanism of peer review. Let me
point out that if you type the ordinary word “inequality” into Google, then
1.3 million web-sites are returned. My research site,
http://utip.gov.utexas.edu
comes in, at the moment, fourth, and
first among those dedicated to economic issues. Jean-Jacques Rousseau is a
bit behind.
posted 10-27-2003